Trickle-Down Economics Must Die. Long Live Grow-Up Economics
Posted: 11/18/2015 2:35 pm EST Updated: 11/18/2015 3:59 pm EST
"Economics, as it has been
practiced in the last three decades, has been positively harmful for most people."
~ Economist Ha-Joon Chang
For over thirty years we've treated
something as fact which is actually false. Economists we trusted to know better
didn't, and so people have suffered and continue to suffer. This pernicious
economic myth is the idea that a rising yacht lifts all tides,
or as more popularly described, "trickle-down economics." If we are
to start running our economy in a way we could one day describe as notably less
insane, we must finally come to see it for what it actually is.
An Undead Idea
This
belief -- that it's good economics to give a relatively greater and greater
share of the pie to the top of the economic spectrum because the absolute sizes
of all remaining shares will grow -- has taken some mortal hits in recent years
by some major players, most notably even the OECD and IMF. In fact, it has now
reached the point such that the idea being left alive in the minds of anyone
makes it a good candidate as an extra in The Walking Dead.
Surveying the data, we'll start
with Wall Street bonuses versus the economic multiplier effects of higher
velocity money, go on to economic growth research in relation to distributional
inequality, and end with what we know from global cash transfer evidence and
the economic effects of billionaires. Let's burn this undead idea of
inequality-driven economic growth with napalm and bury it in concrete, shall
we?
This chart alone is perhaps enough
to warrant a trip to the nearest window to shout out, "I'm mad as
hell, and I'm not going to take this anymore!"
Wall Street earned twice as much in
year-end bonuses alone as all full-time minimum wage workers combined earned
the entire year.
What Mother Jones
neglected to mention however is something that goes well beyond "fucked
up," and something which did not go unmentioned in a piece by the Institute for Policy Studies after
identical news the year before.
Every extra dollar going into the
pockets of low-wage workers, standard economic multiplier models tell us, adds about
$1.21 to the national economy. Every extra dollar going into the pockets of a
high-income American, by contrast, only adds about 39 cents to the GDP. These
pennies add up considerably on $26.7 billion in earnings. If the $26.7 billion
Wall Streeters pulled in on bonuses in 2013 had gone to minimum wage workers
instead, our GDP would have grown by about $32.3 billion, over triple
the $10.4 billion boost expected from the Wall Street bonuses.
Yeah, you read that right. In 2013,
by giving huge bonuses to those on Wall Street instead of low-wage workers, we
actively prevented the creation of about $22 billion in additional national
wealth. In 2014, we did the same thing, but to an even larger degree,
preventing about $23 billion in additional national wealth
that would have otherwise been created, had those billions in bonuses been
distributed to low-income earners instead.
Year after year, we prevent new
wealth creation. Why is this the case? What causes such a big difference in
wealth creation, such that money at the bottom is over three
times more effective at driving economic growth than money at
the top?
Well, economists call it the
"multiplier effect" whose origins are in what's called the "marginal propensity to consume." It describes how
those with little money spend it quickly and those with lots of money don't.
Fast Money vs. Slow Money
Simply put, monetary exchanges have
a frequency rate -- a "velocity" -- and this rate is far higher at the
bottom than at the top. When you have a lot of money, each individual dollar,
for the most part, just kind of sits around. Sure, it may be put to use
eventually, but these dollars are more like gold coins inside Scrooge McDuck's
bank vault. Occasionally they get swam in, but they're really just there to be
counted and look shiny. Additionally, they can even get sent overseas to sit
around in vaults elsewhere.
Looking at the latest money
velocity charts and comparing today's numbers to the historical record is all
one needs to see what happens to the overall rate of market exchanges when we
start letting the top accumulate more and more of the total money supply.
We are exchanging the dollars in
our money supply more slowly than even during the Great Depression.
The result has been an economy growing more and more tilted every day, such
that even Disney itself, a company built on middle class consumption, is actively leaving it behind in an accelerating sprint
towards that shrinking population with money to spend in greater and greater
amounts.
The velocity of each dollar in our
total money supply is now lower than has ever been recorded in all of U.S.
history.
Meanwhile, that shrinking amount of
money that's still accessible in hands at the bottom? It's changing hand after
hand, and quickly. That dollar is no coin in a bank vault. It helps buy a
gallon of milk, which pays a cashier, which helps buy a haircut, which pays a
hair stylist, which helps buy a ticket to a movie, which pays a concession
stand worker, which helps buy a dinner for two, and on and on it goes, like a
fiery hot lava potato.
Section 2: Subtraction and
Addition
It's not just that someone with
little money has enough money to spend that expands an economy. The most
effectual part is that a dollar is also removed from the hand overflowing with dollars.
Who knew Robin Hood oversaw such an effective economic stimulus program? But
that's how it works and also in a way that stabilizes the entire economy
according to a new model built by Ricardo Reis and Alistair McKay of
Columbia University and Boston University.
"It's the redistribution that
has a lot of kick," Reis said in an interview with Bloomberg. "The usual argument for
transfers is basically Keynesian. We find that has very low impact in our
model."
According to Reis and McKay, there
is no better way of creating a more stable economy than to expand
tax-and-transfer programs that specifically reduce inequality, like food stamps
and social insurance.
A healthy economy is not one of
extreme inequality, but one where everyone has enough money to spend into it,
to the point they can start saving what they don't need to spend.
When the only ones capable of
making exchanges are a small percentage of the population, the entire economy
suffers because the many are excluded for the benefit of the few, but this
benefit too is an illusion. There is no real benefit.
Pretending otherwise is like thinking that cutting off the blood in your body
to everything except the brain is good for business. It's not. It's good for
gangrene.
OECD Findings
In a December 2014 report titled,
"Trends in Income Inequality and its Impact on Economic Growth," the OECD found that inequality slows economic growth.
"Rising inequality is
estimated to have knocked more than 10 percentage points off growth in Mexico
and New Zealand over the past two decades up to the Great Recession. In Italy,
the United Kingdom and the United States, the cumulative growth rate
would have been six to nine percentage points higher had income disparities not
widened, but also in Sweden, Finland and Norway, although from low
levels. On the other hand, greater equality helped increase GDP per capita in
Spain, France and Ireland prior to the crisis.
One sentence from the report stands
out in particular, as something absolutely vital to focus on to achieve strong
economic growth.
The impact of inequality on
growth stems from the gap between the bottom 40 percent with the rest of
society, not just the poorest 10 percent. Anti-poverty programs will not be
enough, says the OECD.
It is not enough to tax and
transfer only from the top to the bottom.
Transfer recipients must include at
least about half of the entire population. The incomes of the middle class must
be increased alongside those living under or near the poverty line, and all of
this entirely at the expense of the top. By not doing this, we all lose, even
the rich.
Between 1990 and today, US GDP grew
from $6 trillion to what is now almost $18 trillion. The OECD is saying that
had we not allowed our inequality to grow alongside it, our GDP would have
grown an extra trillion dollars. And had we reduced our inequality, our GDP
would now likely be somewhere north of $20 trillion instead of $17.7
trillion.
But we didn't do that. We instead
shoveled money hand over fist into the pockets of those with already
overstuffed pockets, and to this day we continue to do so. However, this
behavior is beginning to be questioned by even more growth experts than the
OECD. The IMF is now asking them too.
IMF Findings
In June of 2015, the International
Monetary Fund upped the ante with an even more damning report on the effects of
income inequality on economic growth than the OECD.
According to the IMF, increasing
the share of the total pie of the top 20% by just 1% (by, say, throwing bonuses
at them) decreases economic growth by 0.08 points.
It actually damages the economy. Overall wealth decreases. On the other hand,
increasing the share of the bottom 20% by the same 1%, increases
economic growth by 0.38 points, that makes it five times more
effective and in the direction we actually want. Similar growth increases are
seen in decreasing amounts for the middle three quintiles, with 0.33 points,
0.27 points and 0.06 points respectively.
In other words, transferring money
from the bottom to the top actually slows GDP. It erases national wealth. It
shrinks the pie. Whereas doing the opposite -- transferring money from the top
to the bottom -- is the equivalent of throwing Viagra at GDP. It quickly grows
the pie. When the bottom 60% get a larger share, everyone greatly benefits,
including the top 40%.
The OECD data points to
redistributing from the top to the bottom 40%.
The IMF data points to
redistributing from the top to the bottom 60%.
No data points to
redistributing to the top from the bottom, which is -- unfortunately
for everyone -- exactly what we've been doing for decades. Redistribution
actively already exists, and it's in the wrong direction for GDP growth.
The United States: Taking from the working poor and middle classes to give to the rich for 40 years.
So this idea that we should ever
let inequality increase because it grows the total pie is completely and
utterly false. By letting inequality increase, the entire pie actually shrinks.
If we want the pie to grow we need to shift some of that stagnant wealth of the
top 20% over to the other quintiles, and the more we shift towards the bottom
and middle, the faster the pie will grow for everyone.
"Policies that help to limit or
reverse inequality may not only make societies less unfair, but also
wealthier." - OECD, 2014
This is a huge reason, if not the
best reason, for everyone to support the idea of universal basic income: increased
economic growth that benefits everyone. By reducing the rate of wealth
accumulation of the top 20% in a way that better distributes that income to
everyone else, we see the potential to build national wealth at historic new
rates.
A Big
Economy
I've estimated before that the total
additional cost required to give every adult citizen a basic income guarantee
(BIG) of $1,000 per month and every citizen under eighteen $300 per month would
be around $1.5 trillion after the elimination of expenses no longer
required with a basic income. This is roughly 8.5% of GDP. (Note: the total
cost of child poverty alone is 5.7% of GDP)
If that revenue is removed from the
vaults of the top 20% where it is sitting stagnant and distributed to the
bottom 60% (no need to alter the distribution for the 60-80% according to the
OECD or IMF), that's about a 2.83% increase for each quintile combined with the
growth from the 8.5% decrease in the 5th quintile. If these are then multiplied
by the IMF numbers per 1% increase, the total combined result is a 3.45% growth
estimate, for a new total GDP growth rate of potentially 6.44% with a universal
basic income in place.
This may sound high, and admittedly quite wonkish, but I believe it's also likely we'll see second and third order effects along the lines of increased productivity, and wage increases through higher bargaining power, which would both result in potentially even larger increases to GDP growth with basic income than the IMF or OECD data points to.
This may sound high, and admittedly quite wonkish, but I believe it's also likely we'll see second and third order effects along the lines of increased productivity, and wage increases through higher bargaining power, which would both result in potentially even larger increases to GDP growth with basic income than the IMF or OECD data points to.
Follow Scott Santens on Twitter:
www.twitter.com/2noame
No comments:
Post a Comment